-
Notifications
You must be signed in to change notification settings - Fork 0
/
OA.tex
1897 lines (1520 loc) · 127 KB
/
OA.tex
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
65
66
67
68
69
70
71
72
73
74
75
76
77
78
79
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
92
93
94
95
96
97
98
99
100
101
102
103
104
105
106
107
108
109
110
111
112
113
114
115
116
117
118
119
120
121
122
123
124
125
126
127
128
129
130
131
132
133
134
135
136
137
138
139
140
141
142
143
144
145
146
147
148
149
150
151
152
153
154
155
156
157
158
159
160
161
162
163
164
165
166
167
168
169
170
171
172
173
174
175
176
177
178
179
180
181
182
183
184
185
186
187
188
189
190
191
192
193
194
195
196
197
198
199
200
201
202
203
204
205
206
207
208
209
210
211
212
213
214
215
216
217
218
219
220
221
222
223
224
225
226
227
228
229
230
231
232
233
234
235
236
237
238
239
240
241
242
243
244
245
246
247
248
249
250
251
252
253
254
255
256
257
258
259
260
261
262
263
264
265
266
267
268
269
270
271
272
273
274
275
276
277
278
279
280
281
282
283
284
285
286
287
288
289
290
291
292
293
294
295
296
297
298
299
300
301
302
303
304
305
306
307
308
309
310
311
312
313
314
315
316
317
318
319
320
321
322
323
324
325
326
327
328
329
330
331
332
333
334
335
336
337
338
339
340
341
342
343
344
345
346
347
348
349
350
351
352
353
354
355
356
357
358
359
360
361
362
363
364
365
366
367
368
369
370
371
372
373
374
375
376
377
378
379
380
381
382
383
384
385
386
387
388
389
390
391
392
393
394
395
396
397
398
399
400
401
402
403
404
405
406
407
408
409
410
411
412
413
414
415
416
417
418
419
420
421
422
423
424
425
426
427
428
429
430
431
432
433
434
435
436
437
438
439
440
441
442
443
444
445
446
447
448
449
450
451
452
453
454
455
456
457
458
459
460
461
462
463
464
465
466
467
468
469
470
471
472
473
474
475
476
477
478
479
480
481
482
483
484
485
486
487
488
489
490
491
492
493
494
495
496
497
498
499
500
501
502
503
504
505
506
507
508
509
510
511
512
513
514
515
516
517
518
519
520
521
522
523
524
525
526
527
528
529
530
531
532
533
534
535
536
537
538
539
540
541
542
543
544
545
546
547
548
549
550
551
552
553
554
555
556
557
558
559
560
561
562
563
564
565
566
567
568
569
570
571
572
573
574
575
576
577
578
579
580
581
582
583
584
585
586
587
588
589
590
591
592
593
594
595
596
597
598
599
600
601
602
603
604
605
606
607
608
609
610
611
612
613
614
615
616
617
618
619
620
621
622
623
624
625
626
627
628
629
630
631
632
633
634
635
636
637
638
639
640
641
642
643
644
645
646
647
648
649
650
651
652
653
654
655
656
657
658
659
660
661
662
663
664
665
666
667
668
669
670
671
672
673
674
675
676
677
678
679
680
681
682
683
684
685
686
687
688
689
690
691
692
693
694
695
696
697
698
699
700
701
702
703
704
705
706
707
708
709
710
711
712
713
714
715
716
717
718
719
720
721
722
723
724
725
726
727
728
729
730
731
732
733
734
735
736
737
738
739
740
741
742
743
744
745
746
747
748
749
750
751
752
753
754
755
756
757
758
759
760
761
762
763
764
765
766
767
768
769
770
771
772
773
774
775
776
777
778
779
780
781
782
783
784
785
786
787
788
789
790
791
792
793
794
795
796
797
798
799
800
801
802
803
804
805
806
807
808
809
810
811
812
813
814
815
816
817
818
819
820
821
822
823
824
825
826
827
828
829
830
831
832
833
834
835
836
837
838
839
840
841
842
843
844
845
846
847
848
849
850
851
852
853
854
855
856
857
858
859
860
861
862
863
864
865
866
867
868
869
870
871
872
873
874
875
876
877
878
879
880
881
882
883
884
885
886
887
888
889
890
891
892
893
894
895
896
897
898
899
900
901
902
903
904
905
906
907
908
909
910
911
912
913
914
915
916
917
918
919
920
921
922
923
924
925
926
927
928
929
930
931
932
933
934
935
936
937
938
939
940
941
942
943
944
945
946
947
948
949
950
951
952
953
954
955
956
957
958
959
960
961
962
963
964
965
966
967
968
969
970
971
972
973
974
975
976
977
978
979
980
981
982
983
984
985
986
987
988
989
990
991
992
993
994
995
996
997
998
999
1000
% \documentclass[oneside,11pt]{article}
% \input{preamble.tex}
% %%% HELPER CODE FOR DEALING WITH EXTERNAL REFERENCES
% \usepackage{xr}
% \makeatletter
% \newcommand*{\addFileDependency}[1]{
% \typeout{(#1)}
% \@addtofilelist{#1}
% \IfFileExists{#1}{}{\typeout{No file #1.}}
% }
% \makeatother
% \newcommand*{\myexternaldocument}[1]{
% \externaldocument{#1}
% \addFileDependency{#1.tex}
% \addFileDependency{#1.aux}
% }
% %\myexternaldocument{OA}
% %%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%% DOCUMENT
% \begin{document}
%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%
% APPENDIX
\setcounter{table}{0}
\setcounter{figure}{0}
\setcounter{section}{0}
\pagenumbering{gobble}
\newgeometry{margin=1in}
\begin{center}
\LARGE Supplementary Appendix for ``The controlled choice design and private paternalism in pawnshop borrowing'' \\[0.5em]
%\Large{Appendix $-$ For Online Publication} \\[1em]
\large \author{Craig McIntosh \and Isaac Meza \and Joyce Sadka \and Enrique Seira \and Francis J.\ DiTraglia}
\end{center}
\appendix
\pagenumbering{arabic}
\renewcommand\thefigure{OA-\arabic{figure}}
\renewcommand\thetable{OA-\arabic{table}}
\renewcommand*{\thepage}{OA - \arabic{page}}
\renewcommand\thesection{Appendix \Alph{section}.}
\renewcommand\thesubsection{\Alph{section}.\arabic{subsection}}
%\renewcommand{\cftparskip}{0em} % NOT NEEDED
\renewcommand\cftsecdotsep{\cftdotsep}
\renewcommand\cftsubsecdotsep{\cftnodots}
\renewcommand{\cftsecnumwidth}{6em}
\renewcommand{\cftpnumalign}{r}
%\renewcommand{\cftsecleader}{\normalfont\cftdotfill{\cftsecdotsep}}
\renewcommand{\cftsecleader}{\cftdotfill{\cftsecdotsep}\hspace{1.8em}}
%\renewcommand{\cftsecpagefont}{20em}
%\renewcommand{\cftfignumwidth}{6em}
%\renewcommand{\cfttabnumwidth}{3.3em}
%\tableofcontents
\etocdepthtag.toc{mtappendix}
\etocsettagdepth{mtchapter}{none}
\etocsettagdepth{mtappendix}{subsection}
\setstretch{0.9}
%\renewcommand\contentsname{} % the empty name
%\begingroup
%\let\clearpage\relax
%%\vspace{-1.5em} % the removed space. Set as appropriate
%\tableofcontents
%\endgroup
%\newpage
\linespread{1}
%\section{ Treatment Explanation Materials and Pictures}
\section{Treatment Explanation Materials}
%\vspace{.2in}
%\subsection{Materials}
\begin{figure}[H]
\caption{Contract Terms Summary}
\label{PaperSlip}
\begin{center}
%\begin{subfigure}{0.65\textwidth}
%\caption{Receipt for client}
% \centering
\includegraphics[width=0.5\textwidth]{Figuras/TicketLenderP.png}
%\end{subfigure}
%\vspace{3ex}
%\begin{subfigure}{0.65\textwidth}
%\caption{Personal promise signed by client}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/Personal Promise2.png}
%\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\scriptsize{
We show a sample receipt that was given to clients that got assigned to the fee-forcing contract (the font and format were changed to protect Lender's P identity). We want to highlight the salience of some items. First the title clearly indicated which contract the client has (arrow 1). Second, in the case of the fee contract it clearly indicates that there is a fee for paying late equivalent to 2\% of the value of the monthly payment (arrow 2). Third, there is a calendar for payments clearly specifying the dates and amounts to pay each month. %The bottom panel of the figure shows a ``promise slip'', the paper that those who were assigned (or chose) to the monthly payment with promise had to sign to make the promise salient. It emphasizes that the client is giving his word, and that the promise is not a legal document.
}
\end{figure}
\begin{figure}[H]
\caption{Explanatory Material}
\label{ExplanatoryMaterial}
\begin{center}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=0.6\textwidth]{Figuras/micas.pdf}
\end{center}
\scriptsize{
This is a (translated) sample information slide shown to clients. The real ones were twice the size of this figure and were laminated. Different ones were shown for each treatment arm.}
\end{figure}
%\subsection{Pictures}
%
%\begin{figure}[H]
% \caption{Some Pawnshops}
% \label{PawnshopPicture}
% \begin{center}
% \begin{subfigure}{0.405\textwidth}
% \caption{Appraiser/tellers inside a pawnshop}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/empenio9_.png}
% \end{subfigure}
% \begin{subfigure}{0.45\textwidth}
% \caption{Pawnshop}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/empenio11_.png}
% \end{subfigure}
%
% \vspace{3ex}
%
% \begin{subfigure}{0.45\textwidth}
% \caption{Pawnshop}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/empenio2_.png}
% \end{subfigure}
% \begin{subfigure}{0.415\textwidth}
% \caption{Lost pawns which are for sale}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/empenio3_.png}
% \end{subfigure}
% \end{center}
% \scriptsize{
% This figure shows pictures of pawnshops in Mexico city. They do not necessarily coincide with Lender P for confidentiality.}
%\end{figure}
%\vspace{.1in}
%\begin{figure}[H]
% \caption{Gold buyers next to pawnshops}
% \label{GoldBuyers}
% \begin{center}
% \begin{subfigure}{.49\textwidth}
% \caption{Gold buyer next to pawnshop 1}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/empenio7_.png}
% \end{subfigure}
% \begin{subfigure}{.49\textwidth}
% \caption{Gold buyer next to pawnshop 1}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/empenio8_.png}
% \end{subfigure}
% \vspace{3ex}
%
% \end{center}
% \scriptsize{
% This figure shows pictures of gold buyers next to pawnshops in Mexico city. They do not necessarily coincide with Lender P for confidentiality. }
%\end{figure}
\begin{comment}
\\
\begin{table}[H]
\caption{Number of pawns balance before and after the experiment}
\label{num_pawns_bal}
\begin{center}
\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/num_pawns_bal.tex}}
\end{center}
\scriptsize
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{num\_pawns\_bal.do}
\end{table}
\end{comment}
%\todo[inline]{removed}
\newpage
\subsection{Survey} \label{app:survey_data}
\normalsize
\linespread{1.05}
%Really force it to normal size and linespread
\normalsize
\linespread{1.05}
\begin{table}[H]
\caption{Baseline survey questions (translated to English)}
\label{baseline_survey}
\begin{center}
\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/transcribed.tex}}
\end{center}
\scriptsize{
Translation of the baseline questionnaire.}
\end{table}
\newpage
We now present analysis of the extent to which the survey-responding sample is representative and balanced.
Table \ref{SS_cond_survey} presents information about survey non-response.
Panel A is a balance table that compares loan amount and day of the week across treatment arms for the subset of borrowers who responded to at least one survey question.
The p-values in the fourth column are for the F-test of no difference of means across treatment arms.
Panel B presents response-rates by question for each arm of the experiment, along with p-values for the F-test of no difference in question-specific response rates across treatment arms.
This panel uses data from participants who answered at least one survey question and went on to pawn on the same day as their survey response.
From the table, we see that loan amount and weekday are balanced across treatment arms among survey respondents and that response rates are likewise stable across treatment arms.
Table \ref{TUT_cond_survey} shows how the estimated TUT effect changes if we restrict our estimation sample based on survey response.
The first row of the table presents TUT results for the financial cost outcome, while the second presents corresponding results for the APR outcome.
In each row, column (1) presents the full-sample TUT estimate and standard error while the remaining columns restrict the sample to borrowers who answered a particular survey question or set of questions.
For example, column (4) presents results for borrowers who answered the two questions needed to compute our measure of ``present bias'' discussed in the next paragraph, while column (9) present results restricted to participants who disclosed their sex.
As seen from the table, our TUT estimates are quite stable across sub-samples defined by survey response.
In each case they are positive and of the same magnitude as the corresponding full-sample estimate, although statistical significance varies depending on the size of the corresponding sub-sample.
For these reasons, we are comfortable relying on data for survey respondents in the empirical exercises that follow.
In exercises that rely on a single survey question, we use data for every borrower who answered that question.
In the random forest exercises described below, we use data for every borrower who answered at least one survey question.
%\newpage
\subsection{More descriptives}
%The second thing to note is that those that are not closed at the end of our sample period have already incurred substantial financial cost, even though they have not defaulted yet.
%Of those who renew, 83\% lose the pawn. Figure \ref{fc_hist}(a) suggest that financial cost is significant, even for those that do recover their pawn. Panel (b) normalizes the cost by loan size. It shows that as a percentage of their pawn, most of the cost comes from clients that do not recover their pawn. For them the cost is between 140\% and 250\% of the loan value. %{The difference between panel (a) and (b) arises since clients who lose their pawn tend to be those that pledge cheaper pieces.}
\begin{figure}[!h]
\caption{Financial cost.}
\label{fc_hist}
\begin{center}
\begin{subfigure}{.42\textwidth}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/hist_fc.pdf}
\caption{}
\end{subfigure}
\begin{subfigure}{0.42\textwidth}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/hist_apr.pdf}
\caption{}
\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\scriptsize{Panel (a) plots a histogram of this financial cost in pesos for all loans in the experiment, stratified by whether we observed that they ended in default or recovery of the pawn. Panel (b) shows the analogous histogram for the APR.
%defaulted (44\%), recovered their pawn (43\%), or whether they are censored in our data (13\%).
We see that borrowers who default incur higher costs; part of this is mechanical as losing their collateral is part of the cost. Most of the APR costs indeed come from clients who do not recover their pawn.}
%\footnotesize{ } \textit{Do file: } \texttt{hist\_fc.do}
\end{figure}
\begin{figure}[!h]
\caption{Behavior of borrowers who lost their pawn}
\label{proxy_naive}
\begin{center}
\begin{subfigure}{0.35\textwidth}
\caption{Elapsed days to first payment}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/hist_firstdays_default.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\begin{subfigure}{0.35\textwidth}
\caption{Elapsed days to last payment}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/hist_days_default.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\begin{subfigure}{0.35\textwidth}
\caption{Payments as \% of loan}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/hist_percpay_default.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\begin{subfigure}{0.35\textwidth}
\caption{Number of payments}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/hist_numpay_default.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\scriptsize
This figure provides more details on the behavior of clients who were assigned to the control group and did not recover their pawn. Panel (a) shows a histogram of days elapsed from the pawn to the first payment, while panel (b) displays a histogram of days elapsed until the last payment. Some borrowers make payments after day 105, the end of the grace period: if they pay all interest owed, they can ``restart'' the loan. This amounts to starting a new loan with the same conditions and same pawn. Panel (c) shows a histogram of the fraction of the loan paid, while panel (d) presents a barplot of the number of times that borrowers went to the branch to make payments.
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{hist\_den\_default.do}
\end{figure}
%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%
\newpage
\section{ Internal Validity}
If potential borrowers disliked being forced into a commitment contract, we would expect a lower number of pawns on branch days where only the commitment contract is available compared to control days. Table \ref{attrition_table} shows that this is not the case. There is no difference at all between the Control and Forced Commitment arm in terms of the number of pawns per branch-day. Although we cannot reject equality across the three arms (p-value=0.21), the Choice arm appears to have a somewhat larger number of borrowers than the Control and Forced arms.\footnote{p-value=0.23 and 0.12 respectively.} This seems to be due to sampling variability. Differences across arms are smaller when for medians, or when we compare the number of borrowers pawning (some borrowers pawn more than one piece). Figure \ref{boxplot_attrition} shows that distribution of loans per day is comparable across arms. The only noticeable difference is that the choice arm has a few more positive outliers.\footnote{If we winzorize at the 90th percentile, the mean number of branch-day pawns becomes identical across arms.}
\begin{table}
\caption{Limited and balanced attrition}
\label{attrition_table}
\begin{center}
\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/Attrition.tex}}
\end{center}
\scriptsize{Each row in this table
corresponds to a regression. The dependent variables are: the number of pawns-loans originated per day per branch, the number of borrowers per day-branch, a variable indicating whether a person who answered the baseline survey (before knowing contract terms) ended up pawning, and an indicator of whether the person that obtained the loan answered the baseline survey. Each dependent variable is regressed in a multivariate OLS regression against the experimental arms indicators (control, forced commitment, choice). The table reports the coefficients on each of these indicators, as well as the p-value of an F-test of the null hypothesis of equality of the three coefficients. Figure \ref{boxplot_attrition}, in the appendix shows a box-plot of the first two variables, showing the distribution across arms is balanced.}
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{ss\_att.do}
\end{table}
The bottom panel of Table \ref{attrition_table} shows balance in a more focused way, given that the surveys were conducted prior to the revelation of treatment status. We find that in no arm did more than three percent of individuals who responded to the survey go on to refuse loans. That is, the overwhelming marjority of potential borrowers did not leave the branch after learning which contract was on offer. Moreover, the extremely small fraction that did leave is balanced across arms. Therefore it appears that the treatments have not induced any endogenous shifts in the composition of borrowers.
A less critical form of attrition is differential refusal to answer the survey questions. The survey was conducted before treatment status was revealed, and we observe loan outcomes regardless of whether the survey was conducted. Our core experimental estimates do not use the survey data as covariates, but the analysis in Section \ref{Paternalism} is restricted to the subset of borrowers who answered at least some survey questions. The bottom row of Table \ref{attrition_table} shows that the survey response rate is broadly similar across arms (about 78 percent).
\begin{figure}[H]
\caption{Box-plot across arms}
\label{boxplot_attrition}
\begin{center}
\begin{subfigure}{0.35\textwidth}
\caption{Number of pawns}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/box_plot_num_pawns.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\begin{subfigure}{0.35\textwidth}
\caption{Number of borrowers}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/box_plot_num_pawns.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\scriptsize
This figure presents box-plot for the number of pawns and borrowers per branch-day across different arms. The solid black line represent the median, while the gray line represent the mean. The blue dots represent an implicit CDF.
\end{figure}
% \begin{figure}[H]
% \caption{Number of pawns and borrowers before and after the experiment}
% \label{line_pawns_before_after}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/after_before_bal.pdf}
% \scriptsize
% This figure shows the number of pawns and borrowers before, during, and after the experiment for the different branches.
% \end{figure}
% \begin{figure}[H]
% \caption{No discontinuity in the number of pawns before and after experiment}
% \label{rd_pawns}
% \begin{center}
% \begin{subfigure}{0.45\textwidth}
% \caption{Number of pawns - before}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/rd_before_pawns.pdf}
% \end{subfigure}
% \begin{subfigure}{0.45\textwidth}
% \caption{Number of pawns - after}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/rd_after_pawns.pdf}
% \end{subfigure}
% \begin{subfigure}{0.42\textwidth}
% \caption{Number of borrowers - before}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/rd_before_borr.pdf}
% \end{subfigure}
% \begin{subfigure}{0.45\textwidth}
% \caption{Number of borrowers - after}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/rd_after_borr.pdf}
% \end{subfigure}
% \end{center}
% \scriptsize
% This figure shows the number of pawns and borrowers before, during, and after the experiment for the different branches.
% \end{figure}
\vspace{-1em}
\begin{table}[H]
\caption{Balance conditional on survey response and question-by-question response rates} %by treatment arm}
\label{SS_cond_survey}
\begin{center}
\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/SS_cond_survey.tex}}
\end{center}
\scriptsize
Panel A of this table presents the same information as Panel A of Table \ref{SS}, restricted to the subsample of borrowers who answered at least one survey question. Conditional on survey response, loan amount and weekday are balanced across arms. Panel B presents response rates to each survey question across arms, along with p-values for the F-test of no difference in response rates across arms, using data for borrowers who pawned on the same day as their survey response.
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{ss\_att.do}
\end{table}
\begin{landscape}
\begin{table}[H]
\caption{Survey Non-response: TUT estimates for respondents to each survey question.}
\label{TUT_cond_survey}
\begin{center}
\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/tut_cond_survey.tex}}
\end{center}
\scriptsize
Some borrowers did not respond to our survey; others only completed part of the survey.
This table computes the TUT effect for a number of sub-groups by survey response, and compares them against the overall TUT effect.
The top panel uses financial cost as the outcome variable, while the bottom panel uses APR.
Each group is defined by the borrowers who responded to a particular \emph{subset} of the survey questions.
For example, column (4) computes TUT effects for the subgroup of borrowers who responded to the two questions needed to compute our measure of present bias, while column (8) computes the TUT for the subgroup of borrowers who provided their age.
The bottom row of the table counts the number of borrowers in each category.
TUT estimates are quite stable across sub-groups and generally similar to the full-sample estimates.
Because standard errors increase as sample size falls, some of the sub-group estimates are not statistically significant.
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{tut_cond_survey.do}
\end{table}
\end{landscape}
\newpage
\section{ Main treatment effects: Additional material}
%\begin{landscape}
%\subsection{Multiple loans}
%
%\begin{table}[H]
%\caption{Multiple-loans robustness check}
%\label{multiple_loans}
%\begin{center}
%\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/multiple_loans.tex}}
%\end{center}
% \scriptsize
% An additional empirical issue generated by repeat pawning is the question of how to handle the treatment status of those who take multiple loans within the experiment. 43\% of borrowers take more than one loan within the study period, and 19\% are assigned multiple treatment statuses on their different loans. The issue of sequential endogenous treatments has been extensively studied in the context of school lotteries, where the convention is to use the treatment status from the first exposure (ITT) \citep{cullen2006effect, abdulkadirouglu2011accountability}.\\
%
% This table provides robustness for our main results for different ways to handling the multiplicity of loans. Columns 1-4 repeat the main analysis of financial cost and APR using the baseline approach from our main results,i.e. it only considers the first visit, while allowing multiple loans for the same-day. Columns 5-8 considers all loans including dummies for the order of pawns for an individual, essentially making the identification within-order. Columns 9-12 pursue the ITT strategy of always assigning the first treatment status to all subsequent pawns. The core treatment effects are robust to any of these ways of handling repeat pawning.
%
%%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{multiple\_loans.do}
%\end{table}
%
%
%\end{landscape}
\begin{figure}[H]
\caption{Determinants of choice}
\label{determinants_choose}
\begin{center}
\begin{subfigure}{0.6\textwidth}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/determinants_choose_commitment.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\scriptsize
The above figure shows the determinants in a bivariate and multivariate OLS regression of choosing commitment. Choice commitment is a binary variable equal to one, whenever subjects choose the forced commitment contract in the choice arm.
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{determinants_choice.do}
\end{figure}
\begin{figure}[H]
\caption{Histogram of payments}
\label{hist_payments}
\begin{center}
\begin{subfigure}{0.31\textwidth}
\caption{Status-quo}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/hist_payments_sq.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\begin{subfigure}{0.31\textwidth}
\caption{Forced commitment}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/hist_payments_fc.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\begin{subfigure}{0.31\textwidth}
\caption{Choice commitment}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/hist_payments_cc.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\scriptsize
This figure shows the schedule of payments for each treatment arm. In other words it records the time after the loan origination when the borrower makes a payment toward recovery of the pawn. We can see that for both the Forced commitment and Choice commitment arm, payments are bunching at the 30 and 60 days, while most payments are done around the due date of the loan (90 days).
%\footnotesize{ \textit{Do file: } \texttt{hist\_payments.do}}
\end{figure}
\subsection{Censoring} \label{App_censoring}
\normalsize
\linespread{1.05}
%Really force it to normal size and linespread
\normalsize
\linespread{1.05}
Some loans in our sample are ``censored'' in that they continue beyond our observation period.
For these loans, we do not know whether the borrower ultimately defaulted or recovered her pawn.
In this appendix, we show that our main results are robust to different ways of addressing censoring.
Our main results, presented above, make no assumption on the default/recovery status of this loans. However, we compute the Financial Cost \& APR considering all the payments done so far. We now consider some alternative approaches.
One way of considering the effect that this issue could have on our results is to make extreme assumptions about the outcome of these loans in the treatment and control so as to bound the possible influence of censoring. In Table \ref{bounding_censoring} we compare the Forced and Control arms, making the bracketing assumptions about repayment on censored loans. Panel A assumes all censored loans are repaid, and Panel D that all default. Because forced commitment causes borrowers to make payments earlier than they otherwise would have, In Panel A we make a conservative assumption. To see why, suppose for the sake of argument that commitment affects payment timing, but does not not default.
In other words, suppose that treatment makes censoring \emph{less likely} but has no effect on uncensored outcomes.
If we were to treat all outstanding loans as defaults--the opposite of our convention--this would artificially inflate the rate of default among control loans relative to treatment loans.
Panel B provides the lower bound for the treatment effect by assuming censored control loans are always repaid and treatment loans never are, and Panel C the upper bound by making the reverse assumption. Comfortingly, even with these extreme assumptions the significance on the main treatment effects never flips and treatment effects on financial cost and interests payments remain negative and significant in all scenarios. So there appears to be no scope for the censoring issue to overturn our main results.
Finally, Panel E of this table conducts a lasso logit prediction model that uses all of the available information on loans that were completed to predict the outcome of loans that were not. This is a best guess of the outcome on censored loans. Using this prediction, we replicate the main experimental results and find that the treatment effect on financial cost increases from -204 (main results) to -264 (censored loans predicted), and the APR from -11\% to -17\%. Hence, while the censoring issue does have a substantial influence on the magnitude of our estimated treatment effects, these checks confirm that a) the core results are robust to censoring, and b) the headline approach that we take to the issue is conservative and is likely understating the true magnitude of impacts.
\begin{table}[H]
\caption{Bounding censoring}
\label{bounding_censoring}
\begin{center}
\resizebox{1.0\textwidth}{!}{
\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/censoring_imp_1.tex}}
}
\end{center}
\end{table}
\begin{table}[H]
\begin{center}
\resizebox{1.0\textwidth}{!}{
\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/censoring_imp_2.tex}}
}
\end{center}
\scriptsize {
Given the censored loans, i.e. loans that have not finished by the end of the observation period, we estimate `a la Manski' bounds for these loans, meaning that we impute all loans to either \emph{default}$=1$ or \emph{recovery}$=0$ depending on the treatment arm. Different panels perform different imputations for the censored loans for all possible combinations for the imputation, and computes the ATE for the same outcomes of Table \ref{main_impact_table}. Panel A, for instance, assumes that all outstanding loans are fully payed. Panel B is the most conservative imputation since it assumes all outstanding loans in the control arm are payed, while all the outstanding loans in the forced commitment arm default. Panel C, on the other hand, is the most optimistic scenario opposite to that of Panel B. Panel D assumes all remaining loans default. The last panel makes the imputation to the censored loans according to the best prediction using a piecewise lasso logit model for default. In concrete, we build two logit models with lasso regularization, depending whether the loan duration is less than 220 days (two cycles) or more than 220 days. For prediction we use the former whenever the last recorded payment was done within 220 days, and the latter otherwise. Both models includes loan characteristics (loan size, branch), and payment behavior (loan duration so far, days to first payment, \% of first payment, \% of payments at 30, 60, 90, and 105 days, and \% of interest payed at 105 days), but the latter model also includes \% of payments at 150, 180, and 210 days. This predictive model achieves an accuracy rate of 92\% both in-sample and out-of-sample.
\noindent Note that in all panels we maintain significant results for Financial Cost as dependent variable, while only in the most conservative scenario (Panel B) we lose significance for the APR outcome. }
\end{table}
\begin{figure}[H]
\caption{Interpolation on bounding censoring for Default}
\vspace{-1em}
\label{interpolation_censoring_imp}
\begin{center}
% \begin{subfigure}{0.49\textwidth}
% \caption{Significance area for APR}
% \centering
% \includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/frontera_sig_apr.pdf}
% \end{subfigure}
% \begin{subfigure}{0.49\textwidth}
% \caption{Significance area for Default }
\centering
\includegraphics[width=0.5\textwidth]{Figuras/frontera_sig_def_imp.pdf}
% \end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\vspace{-1em}
\scriptsize {The next figure aims to answer the following question: For how many loans in the control arm can we impute recovery, and for how many in the treatment arm can we impute default and still have significance?
This figure shows exactly the boundary separating significance when we vary the percentage of imputed censored loans with recovery and default respectively for control and treatment. Each corner in the square will correspond to one of the panels from the Table \ref{bounding_censoring}. For instance, the origin is the best-case scenario (Panel C) and the point (100,100) (Panel B) is the worst-case scenario. Thus we can think of this graph as an `interpolation' from the four extreme cases. The `x' indicates the proportions imputed by the lasso logit model, and the different lines correspond to setting different significance levels. We do not include the plot for APR nor financial cost, since for any imputation we still have significant results.}
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{interpolation_censoring_imp.do}
\end{figure}
\begin{figure}[H]
\caption{Survival graph}
\vspace{-2em}
\label{survival_graph}
\begin{center}
\begin{subfigure}{0.49\textwidth}
\caption{Ended contract}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/survival_graph_ended.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\begin{subfigure}{0.49\textwidth}
\caption{Recovery}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/survival_graph_unpledge.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\vspace{-1em}
\scriptsize This Figure shows the CDF of loan completion either default or recovery in Panel (a), or loan recovery in Panel (b), by the number of days since first pawn.
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{survival\_graph.do}
\end{figure}
\begin{figure}[H]
\caption{\% of payment over time}
\vspace{-2em}
\label{porc_payment_over_time}
\begin{center}
\begin{subfigure}{0.49\textwidth}
\caption{Unconditional}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/cumulative_porc_pay_time.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\begin{subfigure}{0.49\textwidth}
\caption{Conditional on default}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/cumulative_porc_pay_time_default.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\scriptsize This Figure shows the accumulated percentage of recovery in time by treatment arm.
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{cumulative\_porc\_pay\_time.do}
\end{figure}
\subsection{Robustness accounting for other costs}
\begin{table}[!h]
\caption{Effects on more comprehensive cost measures}
\label{table_robustness_fc}
\begin{center}
\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/fc_robustness.tex}}
\end{center}
\scriptsize{ This table augments the measure of financial cost presented in Table \ref{main_impact_table} with measures of transaction costs, subjective costs, and adjustments for liquidity costs. Panel A reports financial cost in pesos, while Panel B shows APR. Columns (1) and (6) replicate our previous results for comparability. Columns (2) and (7) of Table \ref{table_robustness_fc} use the subjective value of the pawn reported by the borrower rather than its appraised value. Columns (3) and (8) adjust for self-reported transport costs per visit plus an entire day's wage, both multiplied by the number of visits that each individual made.\footnote{For clients who did not complete the individual survey, we adjust using the mean self-reported transport cost among respondents of the respective branch.} Columns (4) and (9) adjust to consider the liquidity cost. Finally, columns (5) and (10) include all three changes together. The main takeaway from the table is that results are quite robust to including a much expanded measure of costs. Each regression includes branch and day-of-week FE. Standard errors are clustered at the branch-day level.}
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{fc\_robustness.do}
\end{table}
\section{ Alternative explanations}
\subsection{Learning}
\normalsize
Table \ref{learning_table} presents information about borrowers' \emph{future} pawning behavior as a function of treatment assignment. Column (1) considers the 228 clients who returned only a second time to pawn again at a day/branch that was randomly assigned to the choice arm. Each of the two rows in this column presents a difference of mean commitment take-up rates, and associated standard error. The first row compares those who were \emph{initially} assigned to forced commitment against those where were assigned to control; the second row compares those who were initially assigned to the choice commitment arm to those who were assigned to the other two arms. In each case, there is no statistically discernible difference in the rates of commitment take-up. Granted, this is a selected sample because the decision to pawn again is potentially endogenous to the initial treatment allocation. For this reason, Column (2) considers the full sample of 4441 borrowers by re-defining the outcome variable to be an indicator for returning to pawn again at a branch/day when commitment was offered \emph{and} choosing commitment. This composite outcome variable is not subject to the sample selection problem (although it is directly driven by the decision to repeat borrow). The comparison in the two rows remains the same: forced commitment versus control in row one and choice commitment versus forced arms in row two. Again, there is no statistically discernible difference in commitment take-up rates in either row. While these exercises cannot completely exclude the possibility that learning plays a role, they provide no indication that the lack of voluntary compliance is simply a matter of inexperience with commitment.
\vspace{.1in}
\begin{table}[!h]
\caption{Effect of Prior Assignment on Subsequent Choice}
\label{learning_table}
\begin{center}
\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/learning_exp.tex}}
\end{center}
\scriptsize
Column (1) reports results for the 228 borrowers who returned to pawn again at a day/branch that was randomly assigned to the choice arm, enabling us to observe whether they chose commitment or the status quo contract.
Each row presents a difference in mean commitment take-up rates and associated standard errors.
The first row (ATE) compares borrowers who were initially assigned to forced commitment against those were assigned to the control condition.
The second row (ITT) compares borrowers who were initially assigned to the choice commitment condition to those who were not.
Whereas column (1) conditions on the (endogenously) selected sample of borrowers who return to pawn again, column (2) considers the full sample by re-defining the ``outcome'' to be an indicator for whether a borrower pawned again on a day when choice was offered \emph{and} chose commitment.
%This table explores learning by focusing on a subsample of borrowers in the experiment and observing their subsequent behavior. Column 1 conditions the sample on borrowers who (a) pawned during the experiment a subsequent time after being assigned to control, forced commitment or choice (the regressors), and (b) when pawning again they went to a branch day when (randomly) choice was available, thus enabling us to observe if they chose the commitment contract or the status quo. in this sample it estimates a linear probability model where the dependent variable is equal to one if the borrower chose the commitment contract in that subsequent `choice' occasion and zero otherwise. The regressors are indicators for the treatment arms in their first pawn in the experiment. Column 1 conditions the sample on the (endogenous) event of pawning again. Column 2 does not condition the sample, but instead defined the dependent variable as equal to one \hl{if the borrower pawned subsequently and choice was available that day and chose commitment, and zero otherwise.}
\end{table}
\subsection{Discount rates}
\begin{figure}[H]
\caption{Financial benefit TUT effect for different discount rates}
\label{fc_discount_rates}
\begin{center}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=0.55\textwidth]{Figuras/discount_effect_tut.pdf}
\end{center}
\scriptsize This Figure re-estimates the treatment on the untreated (TUT) effect from Table \ref{tot_tut}, introducing a daily discount factor in the definition of financial benefit. The discount factor reflects time preference, i.e.\ the fact that payments made in the present are more costly for the borrower. At a given annual discount rate in percentage points (x-axis) the solid line gives the adjusted TUT and the shaded regions 90\% \& 95\% confidence bands. A discount factor of one corresponds to the estimate from Table \ref{tot_tut}. For higher discount rates, the adjusted financial cost will be higher, so the financial cost \emph{savings} will be lower. As seen from the figure, borrowers would need to face unrealistically large discount rates to reverse our headline result of a large, positive, and statistically significant TUT effect.
%It estimates the effect of the treatment arms for different discount factors, where a discount factor of 1 corresponds exactly to the estimate of column 1 of Table \ref{main_impact_table}. Because the commitment contract induces earlier payments, this adjusted financial cost will be higher, and thus financial savings will be lower. This figure shows the range of estimated effects and their confidence intervals, where the discount rate used is ploted in the x-axis annualized. %\textit{Do file: } \texttt{discounted\_noeffect.do}
\end{figure}
\begin{comment}
\vspace{.2in}
\begin{table}[H]
\caption{FOSD by demographic groups \textcolor{red}{\hl{MAY NEED UPDATING}}}
\label{stochastic_dominance}
\begin{center}
\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/dominance.tex}}
\end{center}
\footnotesize
This table does two things. First, it tests whether the observed empirical distribution of financial cost is well approximated by a log normal. It does this using two tests, the Anderson-Darling and the Kolmogorov-Smirnoff tests. Second, it fits a log normal distribution by maximum likelihood to observed empirical distribution of financial cost, separately for the fee-forcing arm and the status-quo arm. Using the fitted log normal, it tests whether the fee-forcing financial cost distribution would be preferred by any expected utility agent using Proposition \ref{lognormal_fosd} below. The different rows of the table do this for different sub-populations. The first row of the table does it for every client in the fee forcing and status quo arms. The ``*'' show that we cannot reject at the 5\% level that both distribution are log normal for any of the two tests. The column entitled ``Dominance'' shows whether any client that dislikes higher cost would prefer the fee-forcing cost distribution over the status quo one, with $\succeq_{1}$ meaning he should (with $\succeq_{1}^*$ indicating the difference is statistically significant). It turns out to be the case that for the overwhelming majority of sub-populations, the conditions of preferring the fee-forcing distribution hold.
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{stoch\_dominance.do}
\end{table}
\newpage
\vspace{.2in}
\begin{prop}
\label{lognormal_fosd}
Let $F$ and $G$ be the cumulative distributions of two alternative log-normal prospects. The following are equivalent:
\begin{enumerate}[(a)]
\item For every weakly decreasing utility function $u$: $E_{F}(u(FC))\leq E_G(u(FC))$
\item $E_F \log(FC)\geq E_G\log(FC)$ and $Var_F \log(FC)= Var_G\log(FC)$
\end{enumerate}
\end{prop}
\begin{proof}
See Theorem 4 in \cite{lognormal_dominance}.
\end{proof}
\vspace{.1in}
\begin{prop}
\label{eq_fosd}
This is a standard result.
\\
\vspace{.1in}
The following are equivalent:
\begin{enumerate}[(a)]
\item For every weakly decreasing utility function $u$: $E_{sq}(u(FC))\leq E_{fee}(u(FC))$
\item $F_{sq}(FC)\leq F_{fee}(FC)$
\end{enumerate}
\end{prop}
\begin{proof} \;
[$(a)\Longrightarrow (b)$] Suppose $(b)$ does not hold. So there exists $FC^*$ such that $F_{sq}(FC^*)>F_{fee}(FC^*)$, Define $u:=\mathds{1}_{FC\leq FC^*}$. Then
\[E_{sq}(u(FC)) = \int u(FC)dF_{sq} = F_{sq}(FC^*)>F_{fee}(FC^*)= \int u(FC)dF_{fee} =E_{fee}(u(FC))\]
which contradicts $(a)$.\\
[$(a)\Longleftarrow (b)$] On the other hand for $u$ weakly decreasing,
\[\int u(y(FC))dF_{sq}(y(FC)) = \int u(y(FC))dF_{fee}(FC) \leq \int u(FC)dF_{fee}(FC)\]
with $y(FC) = F_{sq}^{-1}F_{fee}(FC)$.
\end{proof}
Note the proof was done in the case of absolutely continuous and strictly increasing distribution functions $F_{sq}$ and $F_{fee}$.
\end{comment}
\normalsize
\linespread{1.05}
%Really force it to normal size and linespread
\normalsize
\linespread{1.05}
\begin{comment}
\section{ Causal Forest and individual predictions of `Mistakes'}
\begin{figure}[H]
\caption{Example of a Causal Tree \textcolor{red}{WHAT IS THE DIFFERENCE OF THIS AND FIGURE OA-17?}}
\label{causal_tree_example}
\begin{center}
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/ct_eff.pdf}
\end{center}
\scriptsize This Figure shows an example of the splits for the leaves that emerge in our data for the Athey et al (2019) Causal Forest estimation.
\end{figure}
\end{comment}
\subsection{Sure Confidence} \label{App_sureconfidence}
\begin{figure}[H]
\caption{Determinants sure confidence}
\label{determinants_sure}
\begin{center}
\begin{subfigure}{0.6\textwidth}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/determinants_confidence_100.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\scriptsize
The above figure shows the determinants in a bivariate and multivariate OLS regression of sure confidence among the non-choosers. Sure confidence is a binary variable defined to be one when people report a 100\% probability of recovery.
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{determinants_sure_confidence.do}
\end{figure}
%\section{ Heterogeneity and Bounds}
\section{Bounds, FOSD and Rank Invariance} \label{bounds_FOSD}
%\subsection{Testing for heterogeneity}
%\label{append:chernozhukov}
%If the treatment effects $Y_{i1} - Y_{i0}$ are constant across $i$, then we must have
%\[
%\text{ATE}(X_i) \equiv \mathbbm{E}[Y_{i1} - Y_{i0} |X_i] = \mathbbm{E}[Y_{i1} - Y_{i0}] \equiv \text{ATE}
%\]
%for any covariates $X_i$ that vary across $i$. If, on the other hand, $\text{ATE}(X_i)$ can be predicted using some scalar function $\tau(\cdot)$ of $X_i$, then the average treatment effect function is not constant so there must be treatment effect heterogeneity.
%
%We operationalize this idea using a two-step approach proposed by \cite{chernozhukov2018generic}. We begin by randomly dividing the participants in the forced arms of the experiment ($Z_i \neq 2$) into two groups: a training set and a test set.
%These sets are constructed to ensure that all observations from a given branch-day cluster are allocated to the same set.
%This avoids inferential problems that could arise from correlated unobservables within clusters.
%In the first step, we apply the generalized random forest approach of \cite{atheygrf} to the training set to estimate two proxy predictors: $\psi(\cdot|\text{Training})$ approximates the untreated potential outcome function, $\mathbbm{E}[Y_{i0}|X_i] = \mathbbm{E}[Y_i|Z_i=0,X_i]$, while $\tau(\cdot|\text{Training})$, approximates the ATE function
%\[
%\text{ATE}(X_i) = \mathbbm{E}[Y_i|Z_i=1,X_i] - \mathbbm{E}[Y_i|Z_i=0, X_i].
%\]
%The proxy predictors need not be unbiased or even consistent estimators of the functions they aim to approximate: the goal of this exercise is merely to find a scalar function of $X_i$ that \emph{accurately predicts} $\text{ATE}(X_i)$.
%In the second step we fit a linear regression model to data from the training set using regressors constructed from the proxy functions $\psi(\cdot|\text{Training})$ and $\tau(\cdot|\text{Training})$ constructed in the first step. In particular, we estimate
%\begin{equation}
%Y_i = \alpha_0 + \alpha_1 \psi_i + \beta_1 (Z_i - \mathbbm{E}[Z_i]) + \beta_2 (Z_i - \mathbbm{E}[Z_i])(\tau_i - \mathbbm{E}[\tau_i]) + \epsilon_i
%\label{eq:chernreg}
%\end{equation}
%where $\psi_i \equiv \psi(X_i|\text{Training})$ and $\tau_i \equiv \tau(X_i|\text{Training})$.\footnote{This is a slightly simpler regression than the one proposed in equation (3.1) of \cite{chernozhukov2018generic}, which involves propensity score weights. Because the random assignment of $Z$ in our experiment does \emph{not} condition on $X$, the propensity score weights in our case are constant over $X$ and hence drop out.} As shown by \cite{chernozhukov2018generic}, the coefficients $\beta_1$ and $\beta_2$ from \eqref{eq:chernreg} identify the \emph{best linear predictor} of the conditional ATE based on $\tau(\cdot|\text{Training})$, namely
%\[
%\beta_1 = \mathbbm{E}[\text{ATE}(X_i)] = \text{ATE}, \quad
%\beta_2 = \frac{\text{Cov}[\text{ATE}(X_i), \tau_i]}{\text{Var}(\tau_i)}.
%\]
%If treatment effects are homogeneous we must have $\beta_2 = 0$. Rejecting this hypothesis establishes that $\tau_i$ predicts $\text{ATE}(X_i)$ and hence that $\Delta_i$ varies.
%Since $\tau_i$ and $\psi_i$ do not depend on the test set, inference for the regression in \eqref{eq:chernreg} is straightforward conditional on the Training/Test split.
%Our estimate for $\beta_2$ is 2.56 with a one-sided heteroskedasticity-robust (HC3) standard error of 0.43.
%Thus we easily reject the null hypothesis of homogeneous treatment effects.
%\todo[inline]{Discuss the results here.}
%\todo[inline]{Issac: re-run this exercise with removing the propensity score weights $p(Z)$. Presumably it shouldn't change anything, but it's simpler to explain what we do and probably less noisy}
%\begin{table}[H]
%\begin{center}
%\scriptsize{\input{./Tables/test_calibration_2.tex}}
%\end{center}
%\end{table}
%\todo[inline]{Some Questions for Issac: (1) How are we carrying out the sample splitting? If we cluster standard errors at the branch-day level, we should take this into account when we split. (2) How are you carrying out inference for $\beta_2$? Chernozhukov et al discuss two approaches: ``conditional'' and ``variational.'' The former is simpler as it conditions on the training/test split. The latter is a bit more involved, since one accounts for uncertainty arising from different splits. (3) What are the details of the random forest procedure employed here? (Tuning parameters choice, etc.) We should put them into the appendix.}
%\newpage
\begin{figure}[!h]
\caption{Fan \& Park bounds for benefit in APR\%}
\label{fan_park_bounds}
\begin{center}
\begin{subfigure}{0.55\textwidth}
\caption{APR}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/fan_park_bounds_apr.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\scriptsize
This figure depicts the \cite{fan2010sharp} bounds on the distribution $F_\Delta$ of individual treatment effects $\Delta \equiv (Y_1 - Y_0)$, described in Section \ref{sec:bounds}, for the APR outcome.
The dark red curve and light red shaded region give the estimated upper bound function $\overline{F}$ for $F_\Delta$ and associated (pointwise) 95\% confidence interval.
The dark blue curve and light blue shaded region give the estimated lower bound function $\underline{F}$ for $F_\Delta$ and associated (pointwise) 95\% confidence interval.
Confidence intervals are computed using the asymptotic distribution for the bounds. See \cite{fan2010sharp} for details.
The bounds are pointwise sharp: at any specified value of $\delta$ the bounds $\underline{F}(\delta) \leq F_\Delta(\delta) \leq \overline{F}(\delta)$ cannot be improved without imposing additional assumptions.
Evaluating the bounds at $\delta = 0$, we see that between 23\% and 97\% of borrowers have a positive individual treatment effect.
This is greater than the share of borrowers who chose commitment: 11\%.
%\textit{Do file: } \texttt{fan\_park\_bnds.do}
\end{figure}
\begin{figure}[!h]
\caption{Empirical CDF: Forced commitment vs Control FOSF}
\label{ecdf_fc}
\begin{center}
\begin{subfigure}{0.49\textwidth}
\caption{APR benefit}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/cdf_apr.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\begin{subfigure}{0.49\textwidth}
\caption{Financial benefit}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/cdf_fc_admin.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\scriptsize This figure plots the empirical CDF of experimental outcomes separately for the control (status quo) in dashes, and forced commitment contracts (solid). In panel (a), the outcome is APR benefit; in panel (b) the outcome is Financial benefit.
The empirical CDF under forced commitment first-order stochastically dominates the empirical CDF under the status quo. This can be seen by examining the dotted line, which shows the difference $(\text{Control} - \text{Commitment})$.
%The dotted line at the bottom of panels (a) and (b) the empirical cumulative distribution function APR and financial cost of financial cost. It does this separately for the fee-forcing contract and for the status-quo contract. The dotted line at the bottom is the difference of the control CDF minus the forced CDF arm. It shows that the CDF of the status quo contract is always below that of the fee-forcing (and this difference is significant for the points indicated by the blue line).
% \texttt{fosd_ecdf.do}}
\end{figure}
\begin{figure}
\caption{Distribution of treatment effects under rank invariance.}
\label{te_rankinvariance}
\begin{center}
\begin{subfigure}{0.49\textwidth}
\caption{APR benefit}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/te_rankinvariance_apr.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\begin{subfigure}{0.49\textwidth}
\caption{Financial benefit}
\centering
\includegraphics[width=\textwidth]{Figuras/te_rankinvariance_fc_admin.pdf}
\end{subfigure}
\end{center}
\scriptsize This figure shows the CDF of individual treatment effects under the assumption of rank invariance, computed from
\[F_\Delta(\delta) = \int_0^1 \mathbbm{1}\{ F_1^{-1}(u) - F_0^{-1}(u)\leq \delta\}\,\mathrm{d}u\]
where $F_1^{-1}$ and $F_0^{-1}$ are the quantile functions of $Y_1$ and $Y_0$.
%The dotted line at the bottom of panels (a) and (b) the empirical cumulative distribution function APR and financial cost of financial cost. It does this separately for the fee-forcing contract and for the status-quo contract. The dotted line at the bottom is the difference of the control CDF minus the forced CDF arm. It shows that the CDF of the status quo contract is always below that of the fee-forcing (and this difference is significant for the points indicated by the blue line).
% \texttt{te_rankinvariance.do}}
\end{figure}
\newpage
\section{ Derivations for Section \ref{sec:randchoice}}
\label{append:randchoice}
This appendix provides proofs of the results described in Section \ref{sec:randchoice}, using the notation and assumptions described in Section \ref{sec:potentialOutcomes}.
To simplify the presentation, we omit $i$ subscripts throughout this section.
We also use the shorthand $Z_0 \equiv \mathbbm{1}(Z=0)$, $Z_1 \equiv \mathbbm{1}(Z=1)$, and $Z_2 \equiv\mathbbm{1}(Z=2)$.
For convenience, the following assumption collects our exclusion restriction and the key features of the constrained choice design.
\begin{assumption}\mbox{}
\label{assump:randchoice}
\begin{enumerate}[(i)]
\item $Z$ is independent of $(Y_{0}, Y_{1}, C)$
\item $D = \mathbbm{1}(Z \neq 2)Z + \mathbbm{1}(Z = 2)C$
\item $Y = \mathbbm{1}(Z = 0) Y_{0} + \mathbbm{1}(Z = 1) Y_{1} + \mathbbm{1}(Z = 2) [ (1 - C) Y_{0} + C Y_{1}]$
\end{enumerate}
\end{assumption}
\subsection{Point Identification}
We first show that the TOT, TUT, ASB, and ASL effects are point identified under the constrained choice design.
It follows that the ASG effect, $(\text{TOT} - \text{TUT})$, is likewise point identified.
\begin{lem}
Under Assumption \ref{assump:randchoice},
\label{lem_randchoice}
\begin{enumerate}[(i)]
\item $\mathbbm{E}(D|Z=2) = \mathbb{P}(C=1)$
\item $\mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=0) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_0)$
\item $\mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=1) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_1)$
\item $\mathbbm{E}(Y|D=0,Z=2) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_0|C=0)$
\item $\mathbbm{E}(Y|D=1,Z=2) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_1|C=1)$.
\end{enumerate}
\end{lem}
\begin{proof}
Part (i) follows because $Z=2$ implies $D=C$ and $Z$ is independent of $C$.
Parts (ii) and (iii) follow similarly: given $Z=0$ we have $Y = Y_0$, given $Z=1$ we have $Y = Y_1$, and $Z$ is independent of $(Y_0,Y_1)$.
For parts (iv) and (v), first note that Assumption \ref{assump:randchoice} (iii) implies that $Z$ is conditionally independent of $(Y_0,Y_1)$ given $C$.
Now, $Z=2$ implies that $D=0$ if and only if $C=0$. Hence,
\[
\mathbbm{E}(Y|D=0, Z=2) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_0|D=0, Z=2) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_0|C=0, Z=2)=\mathbbm{E}(Y_0|C=0)
\]
establishing part (iv).
For part (v) $Z=2$ implies that $D=1$ if and only if $C=1$ and hence
\[
\mathbbm{E}(Y|D=1, Z=2) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_1|D=1, Z=2) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_1|C=1, Z=2)= \mathbbm{E}(Y_1|C=1). %\qedhere
\]
\end{proof}
\begin{prop}
Under Assumption \ref{assump:randchoice},
\begin{enumerate}[(i)]
\item $\text{TOT} \equiv \mathbbm{E}(Y_1 - Y_0|C=1) = \displaystyle \frac{\mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=2) - \mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=0)}{\mathbbm{E}(D|Z=2)}$
\item $\text{TUT} \equiv \mathbbm{E}(Y_1 - Y_0|C=0) = \displaystyle \frac{\mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=1) - \mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=2)}{1 - \mathbbm{E}(D|Z=2)}$
\item $\text{ASB} \equiv \mathbbm{E}(Y_0|C=1) - \mathbbm{E}(Y_0|C=0) = \displaystyle \frac{\mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=0) - \mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=2,D=0)}{\mathbbm{E}(D|Z=2)}$
\item $\text{ASL} \equiv \mathbbm{E}(Y_1|C=1) - \mathbbm{E}(Y_1|C=0) = \displaystyle \frac{\mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=2,D=1) - \mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=1)}{1 - \mathbbm{E}(D|Z=2)}$.
\end{enumerate}
\end{prop}
\begin{proof}
For parts (i) and (iii) we require an expression for $\mathbbm{E}(Y_0|C=1)$ in terms of the observables $(Y, D, Z)$.
By Lemma \ref{lem_randchoice}(ii) and iterated expectations
\[
\mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=0) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_0) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_0|C=0) \mathbbm{P}(C=0) + \mathbbm{E}(Y_0|C=1) \mathbbm{P}(C=1).
\]
Re-arranging and substituting Lemma \ref{lem_randchoice}(i) and (iv),
\begin{align}
\mathbbm{E}(Y_0|C=1) &= \frac{\mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=0) - \mathbbm{E}(Y_0|C=0) \mathbbm{P}(C=0)}{\mathbbm{P}(C=1)}\nonumber\\
&= \frac{\mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=0) - \mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=2,D=0) \mathbbm{E}(1 - D|Z=2)}{\mathbbm{E}(D|Z=2)}.
\label{eq:Y0C1}
\end{align}
Part (i) follows by combining \eqref{eq:Y0C1} with Lemma \ref{lem_randchoice}(v) and simplifying; part (iii) follows by combining \eqref{eq:Y0C1} with Lemma \ref{lem_randchoice}(iv) and simplifying.
Similarly, for parts (ii) and (iv) we require an expression for $\mathbbm{E}(Y_1|C=0)$ in terms of observables.
By Lemma \ref{lem_randchoice}(iii) and iterated expectations,
\[
\mathbbm{E}(Y|Z=1) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_1) = \mathbbm{E}(Y_1|C=0)\mathbbm{P}(C=0) + \mathbbm{E}(Y_1|C=1) \mathbbm{P}(C=1).
\]
Re-arranging and substituting Lemma \ref{lem_randchoice}(i) and (v),
\begin{align}
\mathbbm{E}(Y_1|C=0)